Manufacturing
Historically, countries moved jobs from agriculture to manufacturing and then to services, writes Karthik Muralidharan in Accelerating India’s Development. The move from agriculture to manufacturing increased worker prosperity for 3 reasons: (1) Enabled specialization and economies of scale; (2) Goods could be exported to other countries, which meant production wasn’t limited by domestic demand; (3) Jobs became more reliable.
India’s trajectory
has been different –Manufacturing never took off because of the kinds of
government policies we had. India went directly into services (think IT, BPO,
Uber/Ola, Swiggy/Zomato etc). One reason for going to services was timing. As
India liberalized, the Internet started to take off transforming “many
non-tradable services into IT-enabled tradable ones”. Another reason was
India’s decision at independence to focus on high quality tertiary education in
English. And lastly, many folks who worked for outsourcing arms of the best
Western MNC’s learnt best practices, how systems worked and were designed, and
went on to form their own service companies with a large employee base
to tap from.
Skipping
manufacturing is a problem though. Manufacturing employs lots of low-skilled
employees, and those low-skilled folks couldn’t find jobs as India grew. So lot
of people remain stuck in agriculture, which is a problem for them as well as
the nation’s growth rate (since agriculture grows very slowly compared to
manufacturing). Manufacturing jobs also leads to urbanization, which has second
order benefits. Large concentrations of people in towns and cities creates
demand for new services and thus creates the next tier of jobs.
So what can be
done to improve manufacturing possibilities, esp. with the world trying to move
some fraction of manufacturing out of China? Making the bankruptcy process
faster, easier and transparent is one measure. It helps by allowing lenders
recover at least a part of their loans when things go bad. As opposed to the
large bad loans that become entirely unrecoverable. Partial losses are
better than total losses for lenders – it reduces their losses and encourages
them to lend a bit more easily, facilitating job creation.
Another measure
would be to ease the process of transfer of land ownership, and make it faster,
transparent and easy to resolve in case of disputes. Plus, the process of
changing the intended use of land (farming, industries, construction etc)
should be made easier and quicker.
We should check
the overall cost v/s benefit to the country of well intended policies. Take
railway fares being kept low. This makes travel affordable to the poor. But to
recover their costs, freight rates are then increased which in turn increases
the cost of goods and makes Indian goods more expensive and un-exportable. This
impacts manufacturing as a whole.
Some of the above
mentioned reforms need to be sync’ed – fixing one problem while leaving others
unaddressed doesn’t help much. Inter-department coordination within the
government has to be improved.
Improving primary and secondary education translates to a better workforce, which then feeds more manufacturing jobs with its attendant benefit. SEZ’s are another area – the ones we have done are service-oriented, but we need to look at China to learn how to build manufacturing friendly SEZ’s, perhaps by encouraging competition amongst states on that front. Another lesson from China is to incentivize the bureaucracy to care for economic growth e.g. bureaucratic promotions can be tied to policies and measures that translated into economic growth (measurable and concrete). In theory, economic growth benefits everyone and can help get re-elected, so many of these measures align with politicians’ interests too.
Comments
Post a Comment